Lecture Notes 5, Option Values (Ch 9) & Trading Strategies (Ch 10) K Foster, CCNY, Spring 2010 |
|
Learning Outcomes (from CFA exam)
Students will be able to:
§ determine the minimum and maximum values of European options and American options;
§ calculate and interpret the lowest prices of European and American calls and puts based on the rules for minimum values and lower bounds;
§ explain how option prices are affected by the exercise price and the time to expiration;
§
explain putcall
parity for European options, and relate put
call
parity to arbitrage and the construction of synthetic options;
§ contrast American options with European options in terms of the lower bounds on option prices and the possibility of early exercise;
§
explain how cash flows on the underlying
asset affect putcall
parity and the lower bounds of option prices;
§ indicate the directional effect of an interest rate change or volatility change on an option’s price.
From
Notation:
C value of American call option (sometimes distinguish between C0 and CT, the value now and value at maturity)
P value of American put option
c value of European call option
p value of European put option
Six important factors affecting option prices:
Look at each:
First, the value of an
option depends on the spread between
S and K a call is worth max(ST
K,0) while a put is worth max(K
ST,0). So if the stock price, S0, rises
while K is constant, then this increases the value of a call but reduces the
value of a put; if the stock price falls while K is constant then the call
price falls while the put price rises.
It works vice versa for K.
Generally higher stock prices result in higher call prices but lower put
prices.
Time to expiration is generally a positive factor, certainly for stocks without
dividends. (If substantial dividends are
paid, which reduce the value of a stock on the day after, then the dividend
schedule can affect the option value.)
American options, which can be exercised anytime, are certainly always
worth more when there is a longer time to expiration more choice can never be bad!
Volatility (or uncertainty) is a positive factor. This might seem odd unless you remember that options are basically providing insurance, and it certainly seems sensible that more uncertainty raises the value of insurance.
The risk-free interest rate affects the present value of the payoffs to options (since the payoff will be received in the future, a higher rate means a lower present value). However since the expected future price is influenced by the risk-free rate, a call would be worth more while a put would be worth less.
Since dividends reduce the value of a stock on the day after, higher dividends raise the value of a put and lower the value of a call.
Upper Bounds for Option Prices
A call gives the right to buy the stock so it can never be worth more than the stock price; c ≤ S0 and C ≤ S0
A put gives the right to sell at K so it can never be worth more than K, p ≤ K and P ≤ K; in fact p ≤ Ke-rT.
Lower Bounds for Option Prices
These are trickier. For a call, consider 2 portfolios: portfolio A buys a call, c, and invests an amount of cash Ke-rT. Portfolio B just buys a share at S0. The value of portfolio A will be, at date T,
max(ST
K,0) + Kerte-rT = max(ST
K,0) + K = either ST or K,
whichever is bigger, so = max(ST,K).
Portfolio B will evidently be worth ST at the end of the period so portfolio A will always be worth more than portfolio B (or equal in value to it), or
c + Ke-rT ≥ S0
so c ≥ S0 Ke-rT
For a put, on the other hand, consider 2 more portfolios: portfolio C buys a put and the stock, so p + S0, while portfolio D invests the cash Ke-rT. The value of portfolio C will be, at date T,
max(K ST,0) + ST = either K or
ST, whichever is bigger, so = max(ST,K).
Portfolio D will be worth K at the end of the period, so again portfolio C is always worth more than D (or is worth the same amount), so
p + S0 ≥ Ke-rT thus p ≥ Ke-rT - S0
Put-Call Parity
We can also note that portfolios A and C have the exact same value, max(ST,K). So their values must be equal, so
c + Ke-rT = p + S0
or
c p = S0
Ke-rT.
This connects the values of
the call and put options a connection that seems reasonable since both
depend on the properties of the very same underlying stock. The excess of the value of a call over a put
depends on the excess of what we can interpret as the expected present value of
the "intrinsic" value, S
K.
We can get some idea of the
rationale behind this by thinking of the value of a call and put, just moments
before the exercise date. A call is
worth the excess of the stock price over the strike while a put is worth the
excess of the strike over the stock price.
So just a moment before exercise, c = max(ST K,0) and p = max(K
ST,0), or to write in greater
detail,
and
so that c p = ST
K in either case. Put-call parity is just the present value of
that relationship.
For American options, a similar result (for non-dividend stocks) can be derived:
S0 K ≤ C
P ≤ S0
Ke-rT.
Early Exercise of American Options
For non-dividend stocks, an American call is never optimally exercised before the expiration date. There are two reasons for this: that the insurance value should be kept for the duration of the period (you would never want to pay for a year of insurance but then cancel after 6 months!) and the fact that the strike price must be paid, so the time value of money indicates that we want to defer that payment.
However for non-dividend stocks, an American put might be optimally exercised early, because there is a maximum of the put value: if the stock price goes to zero then the put is worth K.
Dividends make the arguments above a bit more Byzantine but don't change the basic intuition.
Trading Strategies |
|
From
Combining a stock position
with an option allows investor to put a cap or floor on payoff. But this has a more subtle implication it can allow us to take another view of
put-call parity.
Consider the profit to buying a stock and buying a put with strike K. The profit function of the stock, S0, is
and the profit function for the put, p, purchased at some cost (so that the investor loses some money if the stock price rises and the put is not exercised) is
so the profit to the combined function is the purple line:
.
The profit to this combination, which I've labeled "Z", looks remarkably like the profit to buying a call, c, at some cost:
.
What could cost be? Recall our formula for put-call parity, that for a stock that does not pay dividends, p + S0 = c + Ke-rT. What is the payoff to a portfolio with one put and one share of stock? That's the " p + S0" part. What is it equal to? A call, "c", plus some amount of cash, " Ke-rT ". So we could also derive our formula on put-call parity from the equivalence of the payoff functions.
This is a taste of a more
general result: if two portfolios give the same payoff functions, then if they
do not have the same current market value then there are arbitrage
opportunities (which, in a perfectly functioning market, would be absent). Put another way, if markets are efficient
then two portfolios that give the same payoffs should have the same value. We'll do some work to show that any payoff
pattern can be replicated with combinations of puts and calls in order to show
that, once we've gotten valuations for puts and calls, we've done all the work
that's necessary any other portfolio can be valued!
We can go through to
re-order the put-call parity equation and figure other payoffs. Rearrange so that S0 c = Ke-rT
p and this says that a short put ("-p")
with some amount of cash has the same value as a long stock ("S0")
and short call ("-c") position.
This diagram is:
where now "Z" looks like the payoff function to a short put. We can keep on rearranging to show that the long put and short call can also be replicated.
Market participants have named a variety of different combinations of options. Among them are:
If options are available at any given strike price, then we can replicate ANY payoff function using calls and puts.